Chapter VI: Promise and Challenges

Promise of National Execution

The implementation of national execution as the main modality for UNDP-assisted programmes, has been difficult due to its rapid and evolutionary nature. Despite these considerable start-up difficulties, the evidence is strong that NEX is well on its way toward fulfilling its promise to involve participating and recipient countries and peoples in the meaningful direction of their projects and programmes. NEX has expanded national officials' sense of programme ownership, increased important aspects of self-reliance, and contributed to capacity building. Logic and experience to date indicate that in the longer run NEX will also strengthen sustainability and increase the cost effectiveness of UNDP-assisted activities. In all of these areas of achievement, however, there are limitations to the progress to date and remaining hurdles to be overcome, but national execution is assuredly changing the way UNDP programmes are formulated and implemented, greatly increasing the participation of a widening range of national institutions and individuals.

Challenges for Effective National Execution

Challenge 1: Develop a Clear Model of Programme Governance

The functional roles of government, UNDP, and UN specialized agencies have become fuzzy during the rush to expand national execution, especially in comparison to the clear delineation of roles under the previous modality. The tripartite relationship of agency execution had UNDP in a traditional donor role, Government line ministries as the recipients and implementers of aid projects, and the UN specialized agencies as the trusted technical and managerial executors of UNDP-funded programmes. Claiming allegiance to the tripartite relationship cannot cover up the fact that it no longer exists in its traditional form.

With the advent of NEX, UNDP now plays a host of roles, including that of partner of government, donor, facilitator of management, assistant project administrator, and performance monitor. In turn, UN agencies are left with an often uncertain, reduced, and fragmented role of providing implementation support in some projects, technical supervision in others, and, less frequently, their traditional full-fledged execution services.

Governments readily accept the ideology that under NEX they have the final executive responsibility for their programmes, only to find that UNDP continues to set the terms, control the funds, and monitor their performance. The widespread notion that the IPF belongs to the government, and that under national execution the government is now in charge, obscures the realities of the continued responsibility of the UNDP for the funds entrusted to it by its contributors and for fulfilling its mandate.

As "executing agency" Government often seems to be owner, general manager, and overseer of its own programmes. In addition, Government often assumes the role of the principal "implementing agency" involving the transfer of management responsibility from one government entity to another, or sometimes combining the two roles in one and the same government institution. The 1992 effort to redefine "execution" and "implementation" has in practice obscured more than it clarified. While the term "implementing agency" is defined in the guidelines in terms of a sub-contractor providing administrative and operational services, too many participants continue to understand the term in terms of the previous usage in which the government recipient ministry was called the "implementing agency".

The time has come to dispel the ambiguities that derive from the recycling of earlier terminology and consider the true functional roles inherent in programme governance and management.

In the purest sense there are two main functions for an organization: Ownership and Management.9 The UN system, represented by UNDP in general and the country office in particular, and the Government, represented by the ministry responsible for coordinating external

assistance, are essentially partners in a joint venture that comprises each approved UNDP programme. As partners/owners they together establish the specific objectives, determine the applicable rules and procedures, and assume ultmate accountability for the results of the development programme. The partners share the same overarching goal which is to maximize the development impact from multilateral cooperation by exploiting the comparative advantages of the UN system. Based on their joint assessment of technical cooperation needs and of the particular benefits of UN system grant assistance compared to other bilateral and multilateral forms of assistance, UNDP and Government agree on the package to be provided by the UN system typically as integral part of a larger national programme.

GOVERNANCE OF NEX


The owners, who in the broad sense lack the specialized skills and dedicated personnel to formulate and undertake specific programmes, determine the suitable agent with the adequate capacity to manage the programme on their behalf. The relation between the owners and the agent is governed by what is essentially a "management contract" which is an integral part of the approved "programme document", signed by both owners (UNDP and Government) and the selected management agent. This agent is normally a national institution, either a specialized government department, an appropriate inter-organizational steering committee, an NGO or a private sector entity. The selected management agent will lead the detailed formulation of the programme under a special programme development agreement. If both owners are satisfied with the design, this agency will be awarded the "management contract" turning over programme decision-making to the agency and making it, in turn, responsible to UNDP and Government for the outcome of the programme.

The programme management agent may enter into sub-contractual arrangements with one or more national or international entities whenever their specialized inputs are deemed necessary. Again, the sub-contractors can be national public sector entities, UN organizations, and/or national or international private companies and NGOs. These relationships are not part of the governance of national execution proper, but rather part of the detailed programme management arrangement which is approved by the owners. These sub-contractual arrangements must be approved by the owners and detailed in the programme/project document.

At the operational level, in order to ensure that the programme objectives are met and management performs well, UNDP and Government as owners will have to monitor management. To the extent that they do not have the capacity to technically monitor the substantive and technical aspects of the programme, this responsibility is contractually assigned to a separate agent (government entity, NGO, private contractor, or UN agency) who is independent from programme management and reports to the owners/partners. The same applies with regard to external financial monitoring. These monitoring agreements shall form part of the basic "programme document agreement" along with the management contract governing the relationship between owners and management. The size and complexity of the programme and the track record of the agent in managing similar programmes determine the intensity of shareholder monitoring. The programme management agent reports periodically to the owners/partners who will seek the views of the independent monitor on programme performance.

In order to implement this overall approach the following tasks are required:

Challenge 2: Improve the Participation of UN Specialized Agencies

UNDP has relied on the UN agencies to assure the quality of UNDP-supported programmes, at least in fields where UN agencies have comparative advantages. Participation of the UN agencies into programmes/projects as provider of technical inputs is still a major comparative advantage of UN-assisted programmes.

UN agencies still provide significant technical inputs to most programmes, and still participate effectively in many evaluations. However, the agencies often have not participated effectively in programme formulations, due to the changed nature of formulation under NEX. The marginal role in formulation compromises later abilities to effectively monitor and evaluate.

The technical role of UN specialized agencies has diminished more than was intended by the Governing Council resolutions. The Governing Council intended to reduce the management role of the UN specialized agencies, and allow them to focus on providing technical resources, especially to upstream activities including formulation, technical monitoring and quality control, and participating in evaluations.

Recommendations for Improving the Mechanisms for Engaging the Technical

Expertise of UN Specialized Agencies

Challenge 3. Specific Policy Suggestions

Policy issues arising from NEX are dynamic by their very nature; these will require a longer time horizon to be elucidated, pinpointed, resolved, and worked into the overall policy framework. To the extent that the suggestions are carried out and evaluation and assessment results become available, policies should be reviewed, revised and concretized and made internally consistent with the NEX modality. The following policy issues and actions on the part of UNDP Headquarters offices will support and strengthen NEX as UNDP moves into the Sixth Programming Cycle:

This study's end users are those UNDP staff, programme directors, and national officials whose in-depth knowledge and facility in the matter certainly exceed those of the authors. The present study does not pretend to offer the last word on National Execution. "In the eyes of the Gods, nothing is final." That truth applies to this study, and to National Execution itself.

 

9 For further reference see Coase, R.H.(1937): The Nature of the Firm, Economica, 4, 386-405; Jensen,M.C./Meckling, W.H.(1976): Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure, Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 305-360; Williamson, O.E.(1984): The Economics of Governance: Framework Implications, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 140, 195-223.